Tuesday, December 29, 2020

The Truncation Of The Economic Lives Of Machines

'Paradoxes' and 'Perversities'
PhenomenonExampleRegion
Reswitching'One good'5
Schefold reswitching3
Schefold roundabout3
Baldone8
Recurrence of technique (without reswitching)Baldone9
Recurrence of truncation (without reswitching or recurrence of technique)Two sectors with fixed capital2
Non-monotonic variation of economic life of machine (without reswitching or recurrence of technique or of truncation)Baldone10
'Non-continuous' variation in economic life of machine associated with infinitesimal variation in rate of profits'One good'1, 5
Baldone7, 8, 9, 10, 11
Increased economic life of machine associated with lower capital intensity'One good'1, 3, 4
Schefold reswitching2
Two sectors with fixed capital1, 2, 3, 4
Baldone9, 10, 11
A lower rate of profits associated with a decreased economic life of a machine'One good'1, 3, 4, 5
Schefold reswitching2, 3
Two sectors with fixed capital1, 2, 3, 4
Baldone8, 9, 10, 11
Decreased roundaboutness associated with a lower rate of profitsSchefold roundabout2, 3, 4

I have been exploring simple models of fixed capital, of the production of commodities with machines that last more than one production period. And in these models, the efficiency of machines varies with age. An older machine might require greater care or produce more of a finished commodity after it has been broken in. The choice of technique becomes a question of the choice of the economic life of a machine. In the jargon, managers of firms decide on whether to truncate the use of machine and for how long.

One might think intuitively, but wrongly, that by first producing a machine and then using it in the production of a finished good that one was adopting a more capital-intensive technique than by directing producing the finished good. Likewise, one might wrongly believe that extending the economic life of a machine increases the capital-intensity of a technique. And that a lower rate of interest (or a higher wage) provides incentives to the managers of firms to adopt more capital-intensive techniques.

One can see that these beliefs are incorrect by looking at specific numerical examples. The table at the head of this post provides examples of curious phenomena seen for the fixed capital. Links are provided to specific examples. (The numbering of regions for the 'one good' example are not consistent over the years that I have been working on models of fixed capital.) I think that some of these effects have not been noted in the literature before, albeit I always suspect that Kurz and Salvadori's 1995 textbook might have a homework problem that I now understand the point of.

The truncation of machines is another aspect of the Cambridge Capital Controversy (CCC). But it was not made much of during the 1960s.

My research project of looking at parameter perturbations to identify fluke switch points and partitions of parameter spaces is hardly exhausted. Some research areas to investigate include:

  • Create and perturb examples of reswitching and capital reversing, for example, in models of fixed capital in which machines operate with constant efficiency.
  • Perturb coeficients of production and requirements for use in models with land, paying particular attention to the order of efficiency, the order of rent, extensive rent, and intensive rent.
  • Perturb coefficients of production and requirements for use in general models of joint production.
  • Revisit the above considering perturbations of relative markups among industries, instead of coefficients of production.
  • Develop computer programs to aid in these analyses.

And besides extending my results, I still need to make an effort to submit much of what I have for publication.

I have decided that applying these results in sensitivity studies of empirical results with National Income and Product Accounts (NIPAs) is probably beyond me. One might consider how perturbations and fluke switch points relate to specific types and biases of technical change. And one might state mathematical theorems and provide proofs.

Monday, December 21, 2020

More On Baldone Example

Figure 1: A Two-Dimensional Pattern Diagram, Enlarged
1.0 Introduction

This post further generalizes an example from Salvatore Baldone.. Like an example from Bertram Schefold, I find that Baldone's example is in a wedge near the edge of the appropriate region in one of my partitions of a parameter space. I have some very complicated spreadsheets that allow me to quickly visualize the effects of varying parameters. Baldone and Schefold were working long before Visicalc, Microsoft Excel, or LibreOffice. Finding these numeric examples must have been tedious.

I think Baldone created this example to illustrate recurrence of truncation. Recurrence of truncation does not necessarily require the recurrence of techniques, but in this example recurrence of truncation occurs with recurrence of techniques. I found it interesting that I could also find here a non-monotonic variation of the economic life of a machine, without recurrence of techniques or capital-reversing.

2.0 Technology

Tables 1 and 2 specify the processes available in this economy. In the first process, labor works with corn to produce a new machine. In the remaining three processes, labor works with corn and a machine to produce corn. A machine one year older than the machine used as an input is jointly produced with corn. Prices of production are defined for coefficients of production at a given moment in time. Technical progress leads to coefficients of production for inputs declining over time. The notation allows for technical progress to be at different rates in the machine and corn sectors.

Table 1: Inputs for The Technology
InputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Labor(2/5) e1 - σ t(1/5) e1 - φ t(3/5) e1 - φ t(2/5) e1 - φ t
Corn(1/10) e1 - σ t(2/5) e1 - φ t0.578 e1 - φ t(3/5) e1 - φ t
New Machine0100
1-Yr. Old Machine0010
2-Yr. Old Machine0001

Table 2: Outputs for The Technology
OutputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Corn0111
New Machine1000
1-Yr. Old Machine0100
2-Yr. Old Machine0010

Three techniques of production exist here at each moment in time. I assume old machines can be discarded without cost. In the Alpha technique, machines are used for only one year. Old machines are used for two years in the Beta technique. In the Gamma technique, they are used for the full three years.

3.0 Prices of Production in Baldone Example

I start by reproducing Baldone's example. I assume labor is advanced, and workers are paid a wage at the end of the year. Corn is taken as the numeraire. For each technique, one can solve for the wage and prices of machines as a function of the rate of profits. Figure 2 plots the wage curves for each technique. The cost-minimizing technique, at a given rate of profits, maximizes the wage. That is, the wage is on the outer envelope. It is not very visually obvious which technique is cost-minimizing, so I have labeled the cost-minimizing techniques. And one sees the Alpha is technique is cost minimizing at a low rate of profits. Around the switch point between the Alpha and Beta techniques, a higher wage is associated with the adoption of a more labor-intensive techniques.

Figure 2: The Wage Frontier with the Recurrence of Techniques

An aspect of the choice of technique can be seen by looking at prices. Figure 3 shows the price of new machines. For all techniques, the price of a new machine is positive for any feasible distribution. At a switch point, the price of a new machine is the same for both techniques that are cost-minimizing. Figure 4 shows how the price of old machines varies with the rate of profits. If a technique is cost-minimizing, the prices of old machines produced by that technique are non-negative at that rate of profits. At a switch point, the price of at least one produced old machine is zero. Baldone's article goes into much detail about prices of machines and truncation.

Figure 3: The Price of a New Machine

The price of an old machine is zero for a technique in which that machine is not produced. Figure 4 shows the prices of only those old machines that are produced in the corresponding technique. In an analysis of the choice of technique with fixed capital, if the price of an old machine is negative at a given rate of profits, the cost minimizing technique must have the economic life of machine must be truncated. Consider, for example, rates of profits less than approximately 4 percent or greater than approximately 63 percent. The price of a one-year old machine under the Beta technique is negative. The prices of one-year old and two-year old machines under the Gamma technique are both negative. Thus, neither can be cost-minimizing. The Alpha technique must be cost-minimizing in these ranges of the rates of profits.

Figure 4: The Price of Old Machines in the Baldone Example

4.0 A Time Path

I now take a first step in generalizing Baldone's capitalism. The rate of decrease of coefficients of production happens to be ten percent in both the machine and corn sectors. Figure 5 shows how the wage frontier varies with time under these assumptions. The maximum rate of profits and the rate of profits at switch points are plotted against time.

Figure 5: Variation in the Wage Frontier with Time

Here, the economy is not viable at the initial time. There must be some sort of low-productivity, backstop technology that was previously used. Figure 5 partitions time into six regions, and Figure 6 enlarges transient regions. Baldone's example is in Region 9.

Figure 6: An Enlargement of the Variation in the Wage Frontier

5.0 A Partition of the Parameter Space

I now let the rates of decrease in coefficients of production differ between the machine and corn sector. Figure 7 graphs the resulting two-dimensional space and how it is partitioned by fluke switch points, which I call patterns. I only label one partition in Figure 7. For the partition between Region 0 and Region 1, the maximum rate of profits for the Alpha technique is zero, and the maximum rate of profits is negative for the Beta and Gamma techniques.

Figure 7: A Two-Dimensional Pattern Diagram

I look at two enlargements of parts ot the space in Figure 7 to get a somewhat more visually obvious understanding of what is going on here. Figure 8 is a blow-up of the middle left of Figure 7, and Figure 1 is a blow-up towards the middle right of Figure 7. I suppose I should say something more about this graph, but I will content myself with Table 3 and one observation. Consider the intersection of the boundaries between Regions 1 and 2, between 2 and 6, between 6 and 7, and between 7 and 1. This point is an intersection of three patterns over the wage axis with a three-technique pattern. I want to claim this intersection is generic, in some sense. I suppose precisely specifying in what sense would be publishable but maybe is beyond me.

Figure 8: An Enlargement of the Parameter Space

Table 3: Results
RegionTechniqueSummary
0NoneNot viable.
1AlphaNo switch points.
2Beta, AlphaThe switch point exhibits negative real Wicksell effects. A smaller rate of profits is associated with a longer economic life of a machine.
3BetaNo switch points.
4Gamma, BetaThe switch point exhibits negative real Wicksell effects. A smaller rate of profits is associated with a longer economic life of a machine.
5GammaNo switch points.
6Gamma, Beta, AlphaSwitch points exhibit negative real Wicksell effects. A smaller rate of profits is associated with a longer economic life of a machine.
7Gamma, AlphaThe switch point exhibits negative real Wicksell effects. A smaller rate of profits is associated with a longer economic life of a machine.
8Alpha, Gamma, AlphaThe switch point at the higher rate of profits exhibits positive real Wicksell effects. Reswitching of techniques and recurrence of truncation.
9Alpha, Gamma, Beta, AlphaThe switch point between Beta and Alpha exhibits positive real Wicksell effects. Recurrence of techniques and of truncation.
10Alpha, Gamma, BetaSwitch points exhibit negative real Wicksell effects. A smaller rate of profits is associated with a non-monotonic variation in the economic life of machine.
11Alpha, GammaThe switch point exhibits negative real Wicksell effects. A smaller rate of profits is associated with a shorter economic life of a machine.

6.0 Non-Monotonic Variation of the Economic Life of a Machine with the Rate of Profits

I might as well illustrate the wage frontier (Figure 9) in Region 10. From low to high wages (that is, high to low rates of profits) the cost-minimizing technique ranges from Beta through Gamma to Alpha. In a stationary state, the machine is run for two years at maximum rate of profits. At a middling rate of profits, its economic life is increased to three years. At an even lower rate, its economic life jumps down to one year. Around both switch points, corn produced per person-year is higher at the lower rate of profits. In some sense, the technique adopted at the lower rate of profits is more capital-intensive, despite the non-monotonic variation in the economic life of the machine. The switch point between Beta and Gamma is consistent with Austrian claims, but the switch point between Gamma and Alpha is a logical disproof of their capital theory.

Figure 9: The Wage Frontier in Region 10

For completeness, Figure 10 plots the prices of produced old machines by technique. For a rate of profits below approximately 10.7 percent, the price of a one-year old machine is negative for both the Beta and Gamma techniques. Thus, neither is cost-minimizing in this range; the Alpha technique is. Between approximately 10.7 and 110 percent, the prices of both one-year old and two-year old machines is positive under the Gamma technique. It is not cost-minimizing to truncate the machine to one or two years in this range. For even larger feasible rates of profits, the price of a two-year old machine is negative under the Gamma technique, and the price of a one-year old machine is positive under the Beta technique. In this range, it is cost-minimizing to operate the machine for two years.

Figure 10: Prices of Old Machines in Region 10

7.0 Conclusion

My methodology for generalizing Baldone's example leads to some complicated graphs. I find a couple of new phenomena that I have not seen in other examples of fixed capital. I think of Region 0, in which no specificed technique is viable. More interesting to me is Region 10, in which the economic life of a machine varies non-monotonically with the rate of profits, without either recurrence of techniques or cost-minimizing.

Reference
  • Salvatore Baldone. 1974. Il capitale fisso nello schema teorico di Piero Sraffa. Studi Economici XXIV(1): 45-106. Translated in Pasinetti (1980).

Saturday, December 12, 2020

An Extension Of An Example From Salvatore Baldone

Figure 1: A Pattern Diagram, Enlarged
1.0 Introduction

This post looks at and generalizes an example of the recurrence of techniques by Salvatore Barone. It is an example with fixed capital illustrating the recurrence of the period of truncation. In the generalization, I find what I call patterns over the axis for the rate of profits, a patern over the wage axis, a three-technique pattern, and a reswitching pattern.

Barone's example demonstrates that around a switch point, a lower rate of profits can be associated with both an increase and a decrease in the economic life of a machine and an increased life of a machine can be associated with both an increase and a decrease in the capital-intensity of a technique. From other examples, I know the variability in the direction of the period of truncation with the rate of profits, the (non) relationship of the economic life of a machine with output per worker, and the jump (from one years to three) in the economic life of a machine with an infinitesimal variation in the rate of profits are independent of reswitching and capital-reversing.

So much for the Austrian theory of capital.

2.0 Technology

The available technology consists of the four processes in Tables 1 and 2. Each process exhibits constant returns to scale (CRS) and takes a year to complete. In the first process, labor and corn are used to make a machine, which, I suppose, I could have called a tractor. In the remaining three processes, labor, corn, and the machine are used to make corn. In each of the first two of these three processes, a machine one year older than it was as an input is jointly produced with corn. Corn is circulating capital and the machine is fixed capital.

Table 1: Inputs for The Technology
InputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Labora0, 1a0, 2a0, 3a0, 4
Corna1,1a1,2a1,3a1, 4
New Machines0100
1-Year Old Machines0010
2-Year Old Machines0001

Table 2: Outputs for The Technology
OutputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Corn0111
New Machines1000
1-Year Old Machines0100
2-Year Old Machines0010

I assume that an old machine can be costlessly disposed of before its technical life. Thus, there are three techniques that can arise in a stationary state. In the Alpha technique, the machine is junked after being used one year; only the first two processes are operated. In Beta, the machine is junked after two years. In Gamma, the machine is operated for its full technical life and all four processes are operated.

I conclude this section by specifying parameters for the coeffients of production:

a0, 1 = (2/5) e1 - t/10

a0, 2 = (1/5) e1 - t/10

a0, 3 = (3/5) e1 - t/10

a0, 4 = (2/5) e1 - t/10

a1, 1 = (1/10) e1 - t/10

a1, 2 = (2/5) e1 - t/10

a1, 3 = 0.578 e1 - t/10

a1, 4 = (3/5) e1 - t/10

Barone's example arises when t = 10. The exponential decay in these coefficients is a description of technical progress as exogeneous.

3.0 Prices of Production

I now want to consider prices of production, given the technology at a point of time, specifically for Baldone's example. I take corn as numeraire. For a given technique, each operated process provides an equation. I take labor as advanced and assume wages are paid out of the end of the year. Given the rate of profits, one can then solve for the wage and the prices of a new machine, a one-year old machine, and a two-year old machine.

Figure 2 plots the wage curves for the three techniques. (By the way, Baldone has a transcription error in at least one of his equations. I was able to replicate his tables with this error corrected.) The cost-minimizing techniques are noted, even though which is on the outer frontier is not always easily visible.

Figure 2: The Wage Frontier in Baldones Example

Figure 3 shows the price of a new machine. At a switch point point, prices are identical for the techniques whose wage curves intersect at that switch point. For example, a rate of profits of approximately 4 percent, the price of a new machine for the Alpha and the Gamma technique is the same.

Figure 3: The Price of a New Machine

Figure 4 is finally an example which is visually obvious. The price of an old machine is zero for a technique in which that machine is not produced. Figure 4 shows the prices of only those old machines that are produced in the corresponding technique. In an analysis of the choice of technique with fixed capital, if the price of an old machine is negative at a given rate of profits, the cost minimizing technique must have the economic life of machine must be truncated.

Figure 4: The Price of Old Machines

Consider, for example, rates of profits less than approximately 4 percent or greater than approximately 63 percent. The price of a one-year old machine under the Beta technique is negative. The prices of one-year old and two-year old machines under the Gamma technique are both negative. Thus, neither can be cost-minimizing. The Alpha technique must be cost-minimizing in these ranges of the rates of profits.

At a rate of profits of approximately 56 percent, the price of a one-year old is positive and the same for the Beta and Gamma techniques, and the price of a two-year old machine is zero under the Gamma technique. This is a switch point for the Beta and the Gamma technique. The price of a two-year old machine is negative under the Gamma technique for any rate of profits greater than this. The Gamma technique cannot be cost-minimizing between 56 and 63 percent. Since the price of a new machine and a one-year old machine is positive, in this range, under the Beta technique, it is not cost-minizing to truncate the machine to an economic life of one year. By the same logic, it is not cost-minimizing to truncate the machine at all for rates of profits between 4 percent and 56 percent.

The analysis of the choice of techniques based on prices yields the same conclusions as an analysis based on the construction as the outer wage frontier. Table 3 summarizes characteristics of the Baldone example. The switch point at approximately 56% is the only one of the three that is not 'perverse'. Around this switch point, a lower rate of profits is associated with an increase in the economic life of the machine, a greater capital-intensity, and more output per worker.

Table 3: Summary of Barone Example
0 ≤ r ≤ 4.066%Alpha cost minimizing.
r ≈ 4.066%Lower rate of profits associated with a decrease in the economic life of the machine, from three years to one year. Consumption per worker increased.
4.066% ≤ r ≤ 55.656%Gamma cost-minimizing.
r ≈ 55.656%Lower rate of profits associated with an increase in the economic life of the machine, from two to three years. Consumption per worker increased.
55.656% ≤ r ≤ 62.732%Beta cost-minimizing.
r ≈ 62.732%Lower rate of profits associated with an increase in the economic life of the machine, from one to two years. Consumption per worker decreased.
62.732% ≤ r ≤ 74.166%Alpha cost minimizing.

4.0 An Extension for Structural Dynamics

I now introduce structural dynamics. I let all coefficients of production for inputs of labor and corn decrease exponentially, at a rate of 10%. Figure 5 illustrates how the variation of the cost-minimizing technique with the rate of profits changes with technical progress. Here, the economy is not viable at the initial time. There must be some sort of low-productivity, backstop technology that was previously used. Figure 5 partitions time into six regions, and Figure 1, at the top of this post enlarges transient regions. Baldone's example is in Region 3.

Figure 5: A Pattern Diagram

5.0 Conclusion

I suppose I should figure out a complete characterization of all six regions, not just Region 3. I now have more examples with fixed capital for my approach to structural economic dynamics than can be comfortably be described in a paper of reasonable length.

I am finding that the analysis of so-called 'paradoxes' in models of the prices of production with fixed capital is an important extension of the Cambridge Capital Controversy. A thorough understanding of the 13-page Chapter X in Sraffa's book only became available in English after mainstream economists had commenced on ignoring certain results.

References
  • Salvatore Baldone. 1974. Il capitale fisso nello schema teorico di Piero Sraffa. Studi Economici XXIV(1): 45-106. Translated in Pasinetti (1980).

Friday, December 04, 2020

Political Novels?

I would like suggestions to add to this list:
  • Benjamin Disraeli, Coningsby or the New Generation.
  • Anthony Trollope, The Way We Live Now.
  • Allen Drury, Advise and Consent: A Novel of Washington Politics.
  • John Ehrlichman, The Company.
  • Anonymous (Joel Klein) Primary Colors: A Novel of Politics.

This is not for Christmas, but some of my personal reading. I am aware that Coningsby is the first of a trilogy, that Advise and Consent is the first of a series, and that Primary Colors has a sequel. Ehrlichman's novel did not make a lasting impression on me. As usual, I find it hard to define what I think groups these together.

Disraeli writing his novels in the midst of trying to climb the greasy pole is hard to fathom:

"The Duke talks to me of Conservative principles; but he does not inform me what they are. I observe indeed a party in the State whose rule it is to consent to no change, until it is clamorously called for, and then instantly to yield; but those are Concessionary, not Conservative principles. This party treats institutions as we do our pheasants, they preserve only to destroy them. But is there a statesman among these Conservatives who offers us a dogma for a guide, or defines any great political truth which we should aspire to establish? It seems to me a barren thing, this Conservatism, an unhappy cross-breed; the mule of politics that engenders nothing." -- Disraeli

Tuesday, December 01, 2020

Triple Switching and Fluke Switch Points

Figure 1: A Pattern Diagram with Triple Switching

In demonstrating the lack of foundation for claims of the Austrian school about the supposed relationships between a greater supply of capital, a consequent lower rate of profits, and a longer period of production, I have so far only presented examples in which the economic life of an existing machine can be extended or truncated. Schefold (1980: 170) interprets a more roundabout technique as one in which a long-lived machine is used to produce a finished good that previously was produced directly without the aid of fixed capital or, at least, with a different and inferior machine. The example in this post extends Schefold's illustration of the difficulty in sustaining the Austrian claim.

I am disappointed that in briefly exploring the parameter space specified by coefficients of production, I was unable to find an example in which wages curves on the frontier were easily distinguishable by the eye. I did like that Figure 1 came out one way I knew could bring about triple switching.

The second, third, and fourth processes in the technology (Tables 1 and 2) constitute the corn sector. In Process II, corn is produced from inputs of labor and corn, without fixed capital. The Alpha technique (Table 3) consists of Process II alone. A machine sector, composed of Process I, exists in the Beta and Gamma techniques. The technical life of the machine is two years. The machine is truncated to one year in the Beta technique

Table 1: Inputs for The Technology
InputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Labora0,1a0,2a0,3a0,4
Corna1,1a1,2a1,3a1,4
New Machines0010
Old Machines0001

Table 2: Outputs for The Technology
OutputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Corn01b1,3 = 1/2b1,4 = 1/2
New Machines1000
Old Machines0010

Table 3: Techniques
TechniquesProcesses
Alpha(II)
Beta(I), (III)
Gamma(I), (III), (IV)

Suppose the coefficients of production for inputs of labor and circulating capital decrease ten percent per year. Figure 1 shows the variation in the choice of technique for a specific configuration of coefficients of production. Schefold's example of triple switching occurs at t = 10. Figure 2 graphs the wage frontier here, in which the wage curves for the Alpha and Gamma techniques are difficult for the eye to distinguish. Figure 3 shows extra profits in operating the second process at Gamma prices. Triple switching is more apparent here.

Figure 2: Wage Frontier for Triple Switching

Figure 3: Extra Profits at Gamma Prices

With this specification of parameters and technical progress, the non-roundabout process Alpha eventually replaces the roundabout process Gamma, whatever the distribution of income. Triple switching appears in the middle of the three transient regions. The patterns of switch points illustrate one manner in which triple-switching can appear. If the pattern over the wage axis were to arise before the second reswitching pattern, the region in which triple-switching occurs would be followed by a region with double switching. With more techniques, one of the switch points could be replaced on the frontier in a three-technique pattern, instead of eventually vanishing over an axis. At any rate, this example continues to illustrate how combinations of patterns of switch points can illuminate the effects of technical change.

In Regions 2, 3, and 4, the Alpha technique, in which corn is produced without the use of a machine, is cost-minimizing at the highest rate of profits, where the wage is zero. Around the only switch point in each of Regions 2 and 4, a lower rate of profits is indeed associated with a more roundabout technique, and the more roundabout technique has a higher level of consumption per person-year in a stationary state. The Austrian claim is also illustrated at the lowest and highest switch point in Region 2. But it is invalidated for the middle switch point. Around this switch point, a lower rate of profits is associated with the replacement of a roundabout technique by the direct production of the consumer commodity.

This numerical example re-iterates that no necessary connection exists between employing or lengthening the economic life of a machine and an increase in the use of 'capital'. Bohm-Bawerk (1959) was incorrect not merely because of the difficulty of defining a quantitative measure of the average period of production. His intuition, and not just his, on how prices work was itself incorrect.

Saturday, November 28, 2020

A Three-Technique Pattern Over The Wage Axis

Figure 1: Wage Frontier for a Fixed Capital Example

This post presents a perturbation of parameters in a 'one good' model of fixed capital. The coefficients of production differ from those in this reswitching example. But the model has the same structure.

Consider a one-commodity economy in which labor and widgets are used to produce new widgets, the only consumption good. (The use of the term 'widget' to designate the single produced commodity emphasizes how unrealistic this model is.) New widgets last several years when used in producing widgets. In this particular answer to Steedman's homework assignment, they last three years. And their efficiency can vary throughout their technical lifetime. Accordingly, Tables 1 and 2 specify the coefficients of production for three processes.

Table 1: Inputs for The Technology
InputProcess
(I)(II)(III)
Labora0,1a0,2a0,3
New Widgets100
One-Year Old Widgets010
Two-Year Old Widgets001

Table 2: Outputs for The Technology
OutputProcess
(I)(II)(III)
New Widgetsb1,1b1,2b1,3
One-Year Old Widgets100
Two-Year Old Widgets010

Firms are not required to operate all three processes. They can truncate the use of widgets after one or two years. The choice of technique in this model is equivalent to the choice of the economic life of a widget. In the Alpha technique, the widget is operated for one year; in the Beta technique, it is operated for two years; and in the Gamma technique, it is operated for the full three years.

The wage frontier is the outer envelope of all wage curves. In models of circulating and fixed capital without superimposed joint production, the cost-minimizing technique, at a given rate of profits, is the technique which contributes its wage curve to the frontier at that rate. The Gamma technique is cost-minimizing in Figure 1 for all feasible rates of profits. Wage curves, when on the frontier, are declining functions of the rate of profits. At a switch point, more than one technique is cost-minimizing. At a rate of profits of zero in Figure 1, the Alpha, Beta, and Gamma techniques are all cost-minimizing.

The single switch point in Figure 1 is a fluke case several times over. It is the intersection of three wage curves, not two. And the switch point is on the wage axis, occurring for a rate of profits of zero. These properties are destroyed by any variation in certain coefficients of production. Figure 2 illustrates variations in b1,2 and b1,3. (The numbering of regions are consistent with this post.) The location in parameter space for fluke switch points, which I call patterns of switch points, is shown. Consider parameters in Region 4, and suppose b1,2 is increased. Eventually, a fluke case will arise in which the switch point between the Alpha and Beta technique is on the wage axis. When b1,2 > 10, this switch point will no longer occur for a non-negative rate of profits. It will only be cost-minimizing to run widgets for two or three years, depending on distribution. On the other hand, consider an increase in b1,3. The switch points between Alpha and Beta and between Beta and Gamma will eventually coincide, in a single switch point at a positive rate of profits. With any further increase in this parameter, it is no longer cost minimizing to run widgets for two years, whatever the distribution of income.

Figure 2: Selected Regions in Parameter Space

Tables 3 and 4 summarize the choice of technique in each region in Figure 2. Negative real Wicksell effects occur at all switch points in the four regions in Figure 2. According to traditional Austrian and marginalist dogma, one might expect an increase in capital intensity to go along with a longer economic life of a widget. This idea is proven to be untrue in Regions 1, 4, and 5. Is the jump over an economic life of two years in Region 1 surprising? Adjacent techniques on the wage frontier need not be near in a parameter space formed by coefficients of production. Continuity in the wage frontier does not imply continuous variation in coefficients of production. In this case, the three-technique pattern of switch points illustrates how managers of firms come to eliminate the choice of the Beta technique.

Table 3: Variation in the Choice of Technique
10 ≤ rr1Widgets operated for one year
r1rrγWidgets operated for three years
30 ≤ rrγWidgets operated for three years
40 ≤ rr1Widgets operated for one year
r1rr2Widgets operated for two years
r2rrγWidgets operated for three years
50 ≤ rr1Widgets operated for two years
r1rrγWidgets operated for three years

Table 4: Summary of Local Structural Changes
1A larger rate of profits is associated with a longer economic life of a widget.
3No switch points.
4A larger rate of profits is associated with a longer economic life of a widget.
5A larger rate of profits is associated with a longer economic life of a widget.

This structure in a two-dimensional parameter space is generic, in some sense. Three partitions of patterns over the wage axis intersect in the start of a ray that is a partition for a three-technique pattern. A corresponding structure exists for patterns over the axis for the rate of profits.

Thursday, November 26, 2020

The LTV And Commodity Fetishism

You will occasionally come upon supposed refutations of Marx's theory of value that I find just ignorant. One might talk about two divers. One comes up with a handful of sand, and the other comes up with a pearl. They have put in the same labor, but their products are of quite different exchange values. Or consider the labor that goes into making a useless product, something that cannot be sold as a commodity on a market. Obviously, labor does not create value.

A refutation can only be effective, at least among serious people, if it attempts to start with an understanding of the idea being attacked. A critique could be immanent and transcend the position it starts with. Or it can end up just rejecting that position.

I am not sure why I included a bit about commodity fetishism in my Frequently Asked Questions about the Labor Theory of Value. Apparently, one of my most popular posts is this one, in which I collect passages in Marx on vulgar political economy, commodity fetishism, and the illusions created by competition.

Marx, in Capital, for example, is analyzing the conditions that allow for a capitalist society to continue, to be self reproducing, albeit with fits and starts. One condition is that labor be distributed among many different concrete activities. For car and trucks to be produced, workers, besides making cars, maybe must be making tires out of rubber and steel out of iron, for example. And trucks or locomotives might be being driven to deliver steel or tires to outside of Detroit. The workers performing these activities are in a social relationship, but they do not see this. Even the managers of firms do not see this. Rather, this social relationship between workers is brought about by selling and buying commodities, such as tires, steel, and cars. Prices bopping about on markets bring about and maintain the relationships between workers. One can see why an analysis of capitalism might begin with an analysis of a commodity.

Individuals living in a self-reproducing society take on various roles, roles that cannot be defined in terms of a single individual or single transaction. Teachers cannot exist without students sometimes listening. And for a teacher to be a teacher, there cannot be just one teacher who once taught one student for one session. Instead, to be a teacher requires that one sometime has taught a student week after week. Nor can a king exist, Antoine de Saint-Exupery to the contrary, alone on an isolated asteroid. Subjects also must exist who acknowledge at least the possibility of sovereignty.

Marx treats the capitalist as 'capital personified'. The capitalist repeatedly uses money to buy raw materials and machinery (means of production) and hire workers (labor power). The workers make a commodity under the direction of the capitalist, and the capitalist owns what the worker makes. The capitalist must then sell the produced commodities on the market. The repeating of this process, time after time, is what makes a capitalist a capitalist according to Marx.

Neither capitalists nor workers calculate labor values. When the capitalist sells commodities on the market, he does not view the commodity as a 'material receptacle of homogeneous human labour'. And capitalists are not required to recognize that the relative prices of commodities express a social relationship characterizing how the total workforce is distributed among their establishments in the various industries in which production goes on in parallel.

Workers pressing for higher wages, less hours, and better working conditions also need no awareness of the labor time embodied in the commodities that they produce and in the commodities embodied in their wage. I take no issue, though, that it is helpful for workers and their advocates to have some awareness of the 'laws of motion' of the mode of production for the society in which they live.

It is a necessary consequence of this analysis that sometimes capitalists will direct workers to make something that cannot be sold as a commodity on the market. In some industries and processes, one expects a certain average failure rate. In oil drilling, for instance, one would expect a certain number of wells to fail. This rate may be lowered by technological advances, such as in controlled denotations and in signal processing applied to returns from various kinds of sensors. Likewise, if all of a company's research and development efforts pay off, it is not doing R and D right.

The deviation of market prices from prices of production is another reason sometimes some commodities cannot be sold on the market for prices that cover the average rate of profits. It is precisely the capitalists reactions to these deviations that bring about the social relationship between workers.

In this post, I have not even defined labor values, much less made any claims about quantitative relations between prices and labor values. I have also deliberately not used the phrase 'socially necessary abstract labor time' (SNALT). I think it clear that Marx thought that none of his claims depended on prices of production being proportional to labor values. I end where one could start with a mathematical treatment of Marx's theory of value. Only then could one argue about whether Sraffa's standard commodity does or does not provide a solution to the transformation problem.

References
  • Arato, Andrew and Paul Breines. 1979. The Young Lukács and the Origins of Western Marxism. The Seabury Press.
  • López, Daniel Andrés. 2019. Lukács: Praxis and the Absolute. Brill Books.
  • Lukács, Georg. 1967. History and Class Consciousness. Trans. by Rodney Livingston.. Merlin.
  • Rubin, Isaak I. Essays on Marx's Theory of Value.

Saturday, November 21, 2020

Visualizing The Effects Of Parameter Perturbations In Models Of Joint Production

A Temporal Path

I have a new working paper.

Abstract: This article illustrates the analysis of prices of production with joint production by a numerical example. The example is used to illustrate the applicability of techniques to identify and visualize qualitative changes in the choice of technique with parameter perturbations. Patterns of switch points are knife-edge or fluke cases in which any perturbation of parameters results in such a qualitative change. This article identifies a new case, called a pattern for requirements for use, in which prices are indeterminate. If the proportions specified by requirements for use are varied at all, this indeterminancy vanishes.

I need more examples of flukes in models of pure joint production.

Wednesday, November 18, 2020

Elsewhere On 2020 'Nobel Prize'

I should have a link to somethingn written by Glen Weyl, not just hom being interviewed.

Thursday, November 12, 2020

Fluke Switch Points At Both The Maximum Wage And The Maximum Rate Of Profits

Figure 1: Wage Frontier for a Fixed Capital Example
1.0 Introduction

I continue to explore the simplest multisector model of the production of commodities by means of commodities in which circulating and fixed capital is used in both sectors. In previous explorations, I locate a four-technique pattern, observe recurrence of truncation, and provide an example in which truncating all machines is infeasible.

I think my taxonomy of fluke switch points and methods of visualizing the effects of perturbing parameters, such as coefficients of production, applies unchanged to models of the production of commodities with fixed capital, maybe with certain simplifying assumptions. So I want to, at least, show fluke swith points of co-dimension one in models of fixed capital.

Every switch point is specified by the condition that two techniques be cost-minimizing at that switch point. The co-dimension is the number of additional conditions that must be met by that switch point:

  • A pattern over the wage axis: The rate of profits is zero at the switch point.
  • A pattern over the axis for the rate of profits: The wage is zero at the switch point.
  • A three-technique pattern: A third technique is cost-minimizing at the switch point.
  • A reswitching pattern: The two wage curves at the switch point.

So I am thinking of how to bring my examples of fixed capital together to show that all of these flukes are available with fixed capital. This post presents a global pattern which combines a pattern over the wage axis and a pattern over the axis for the rate of profits.

2.0 Technology

Table 1 specifies the coefficients of production for the example. In both the machine sector and the corn sector, an old machine cannot be transferred to the other sector. Corn is the consumption good and also acts as circulating capital. This is the simplest mutli-sectoral structure with both circulating and fixed capital in all sectors. The available techniques are defined in Table 2, unchanged from previous posts.

Table 1: Coefficients of Production for The Technology
InputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Labor1/10843/401
Corn0.5488007121.74435840.1250.282386
New Machines1010
Old Machines A0100
Old Machines B0001
Outputs
Corn0010.56
New Machines25/200
Old Machines A1000
Old Machines B0010

Table 2: Techniques
TechniqueProcesses
AlphaI, III
BetaI, II, III
GammaI, III, IV
DeltaI, II, III, IV

3.0 Some Observations on Prices

The choice of technique can be analyzed by the construction of the wage frontier. Corn is the numeraire, and wages are assumed to be paid out of the surplus at the end of the year. As shown in Figure 1 above, the Gamma technique is cost-minimizing at any possible distribution of income. The economic life of a machine is truncated in the machine sector and operated for the full two years in the corn sector. At a rate of profits of zero, it is also cost-minimizing to truncate the machine in the corn sector. At a maximum rate of profits, it is also cost-minimizing to operate the machine for the full two years in the machine sector.

The analysis of the choice of technique is re-inforced by looking at prices. Figure 2 plots the price of a new machine as a function of the rate of profits, for all four techniques. At a switch point, the price of a new machine is the same for both techniques cost-minimizing at that rate of profits.

Figure 2: Price of New Machine

Figure 3 plots the price of an old machine in the machine sector. This price is zero for the Alpha and Gamma techniques, in which the economic life of the machine in the machine sector is truncated to one year. Up to the maximum rate of profits, the price of this type of old machine is negative for the Beta and Delta techniques. Thus, these techniques are not cost-minimizing. If either one of these techniques was in operation, managers of firms would be incentivized to truncate the operation of the machine after one year in the machine sector. At the switch point at the maximum rate of profits, the price of the old machine is zero. Thus, the machine could be operated for two years in the machine sector when the workers live on air.

Figure 3: Price of Old Machines in Machine Sector

Figure 4 shows the price of an old machine in the corn sector. Here the price of an old machine is zero for the Alpha and Beta techniques. The switch points are shown.

Figure 4: Price of Old Machines in Corn Sector

4.0 Perturbing Coeffients of Production for Circulating Capital Needed in Machine Sector

I now look at a slice of parameter space around the fluke case above. Consider small variations in a1,1 and a1,2, the bushels of corn need for input for a unit level of operation of the processes in the machine sector. At a unit level, these processes operate with a new machine and a one-year old machine, respectively, to produce new machines for use in either sector.

Figure 5 shows this slice of the parameter space around the fluke switch points in Figure 1. Variation in a1,2 has no effect on the wage curves for the Alpha and Gamma techniques. Hence, the pattern over the wage axis is a vertical line in the figure. The pattern over the axis for the rate of profits is a diagonal line. The figure shows which techniques are cost-minimizing in which of the four 'quadrants' in which I have partitioned the parameter space.

Figure 5: Selected Regions in Parameter Space

Tables 3 and 4 summarize this local analysis. Around all switch points in illustrated regions of the parameter space, a lower rate of profits is associated with greater net output per person-year. In some sense, a lower rate of profits is associated, in this example, with the adoption of a more capital-intensive technique. But, for all switch points, examined here this increase in the amount of 'capital' used per worker is associated with a decrease in the economic life of a machine, in one sector or the other.

Table 3: Variation in the Choice of Technique
10 ≤ rr1Operation of machine truncated in both sectors.
r1rr2Operation of machine truncated after 1 year in machine sector. Operated for 2 years in corn sector.
r1rrδMachine operated for 2 years in both sectors.
20 ≤ rr1Operation of machine truncated after 1 year in machine sector. Operated for 2 years in corn sector.
r1rrδMachine operated for 2 years in both sectors.
30 ≤ rr1Operation of machine truncated in both sectors.
r1rrγOperation of machine truncated after 1 year in machine sector. Machine operated for 2 years in corn sector.
40 ≤ rrγOperation of machine truncated after 1 year in machine sector. Machine operated for 2 years in corn sector.

Table 4: Summary of Local Structural Changes
1Larger rate of profits associated with longer economic life of machine in both sectors.
2Larger rate of profits associated with longer economic life of machine in machine sector.
3Larger rate of profits associated with longer economic life of machine in corn sector.
4No switch points.

5.0 Conclusion

So that is another example of patterns around the wage axis and the axis for the rate of profits. I still have not found in this particular model examples of reswitching or capital-reversing. But I have such examples in other models of fixed capital. The above example, however, re-iterates that no connection exists between lengthening the economic life of a machine and an increase in the supply of 'capital'. Bohm-Bawerk was not incorrect merely because of the difficulty of defining a measure of the average period of production. His intuition, and not just his, on how prices work was itself incorrect.

Monday, November 09, 2020

Fields Impacted By The Cambridge Capital Controversy (CCC)

Some of these should have been more impacted:

  • Macroeconomics: Measures of Total Factor Productivity, every model with an aggregate production function, and a belief that business cycles are to be explained by sticky or rigid prices or other imperfections are all shown to be questionable.
  • Marxist economics: Steedman's Marx after Sraffa made a splash, with many writing afterwards. Lately, I've read a bit of Riccardo Bellofiore, but a bibliography here could go on and on.
  • Monetary economics: Sraffa's work undermines the concept of the natural rate of interest and the concept of a neutral monetary policy. Colin Rogers' Money, interest and capital: A Study in the foundations of monetary theory goes into this.
  • Labor economics: Here I point to my own stuff.
  • Theory of the firm: Opocher and Steedman's Full Industry Equilibrium: A Theory of the Industrial Long Run is an adequate illustration.
  • Industrial Organization: I have been working on a contribution here.
  • The theory of international trade: Mainwaring, Metcalfe, Parrinello, and Steedman have early contributions in this area.
  • Spatial or regional economics: I'll mention Sheppard and Barnes's textbook The Capitalist Space Economy: Geographical Analysis After Ricardo, Marx, and Sraffa and the work of Walter Isard with different regions being modeled by interacting Leontief matrices.
  • Environmental or ecological economics: I think of Robin Hahnel's recent work on throughput or Richard England (1986) drawing connections between ecological costs and the functional distribution of income.

I do not claim that the above list is complete.

Thursday, November 05, 2020

Infeasibility Of All Machines Truncated

Figure 1: Factor Wage Curves For Feasible Techniques

There are 12 coefficients that can be varied in my minimum multisector model in which production in all sectors can require both fixed and circulating capital. I do not think I am being very orderly in exploring this twelve-dimensional space.

This is a fluke case in which the maximum rate of profits is zero for both the Alpha and the Beta techniques. If only new machines are used as means of production in producing new machines and in producing corn, no surplus product is available to pay out as wages and profits. Likewise, if a machine is run for its full physical lifetime of two years in the machine sector, but truncated in the corn sector, no surplus product is, once again, available. But this is a feasible technology in that a surplus product is available when machines are operated for a full two years in the corn sector. (If a1, 1 and a1, 2 are slightly increased, the maximum rate of profits is negative for both the Alpha and Gamma techniques. Then this would be a non-fluke case.)

Managers of firms choose among feasible techniques by deciding whether or not to operate machines for two years, or to truncate their use, in the machine sector. As shown by the wage frontier above, their decision varies with the distribution of income. Baldone (1980) notes the possibility that for a viable technology with fixed capital, the truncation of the economic life of a machine may result in a non-viable technology. In an already long paper, he does not have a numerical example, however. By the way, Baldone has an appendix with a numerical example of the recurrence of truncation.

For completeness, Table 1 specifies the coefficients of production. I also define the techniques, which are unchanged from previous posts exploring this model. I would be impressed if somewhere in this twelve-dimensional space, almost all phenomena noted in the literature for models of fixed capital and new cases could be found. I have yet to locate cases of reswitching in this model. By definition, I will not be able to find a 'one-good' model with reswitching in this model (albeit what happens if the coefficients of production are the same in the two sectors, perhaps extended to have the machine last three years?).

Table 1: Coefficients of Production for The Technology
InputProcess
(I)(II)(III)(IV)
Labor1/10843/401
Corn0.8752.18750.1250.282386
New Machines1010
Old Machines A0100
Old Machines B0001
Outputs
Corn0010.56
New Machines25/200
Old Machines A1000
Old Machines B0010

Table 2: Techniques
TechniqueProcesses
AlphaI, III
BetaI, II, III
GammaI, III, IV
DeltaI, II, III, IV

References
  • Salvatore Baldone (1980) Fixed capital in Sraffa's theoretical scheme. Trans. in Pasinetti (1980).
  • Christian Bidard (2020) The wage-minimisation property. Working paper 2020-17.
  • Luigi L. Pasinetti, ed. (1980) Essays on the Theory of Joint Production. New York: Columbia University Press.
  • Bertram Schefold (1980) Fixed capital as a joint proudct and the analysis of accumulation with different forms of technical progress. Trans. in Pasinetti (1980).
  • Paolo Varri (1980) Prices, rate of profit and life of machines in Sraffa's fixed capital model. Trans. in Pasinetti (1980).

Tuesday, November 03, 2020

Recurrence Of Truncation In A Perturbation Analysis

Figure 1: Variation of Choice Of Technique with a Coefficient of Production

This post continues the analysis of this example. The coefficients of production and the techniques are the same as in the linked post, except here I consider the results of varying a1, 2, the amount of corn needed as circulating capital in operating Process II at unit level. Figure 1 above shows how the choice of technique varies with this parameter. This is a two-sector model, in which new machines and corn are produced in both sectors. Corn acts as circulating capital, as the sole consumption good, and as the numeraire. Machines act as fixed capital. Managers of firms have the ability to run machines for two years in both sectors, but old machines cannot be transferred between sectors.

Table 1: Variation in the Choice of Technique
10 ≤ rr1Operation of machine truncated in both sectors.
r1rrβMachine operated for 2 years in machine sector. Truncated after 1 year in corn sector.
20 ≤ rr1Operation of machine truncated in both sectors.
r1rr2Operation of machine truncated after 1 year in machine sector. Machine operated for 2 years in corn sector.
r2rr3Machine operated for two years in both sectors.
r3rrβMachine operated for 2 years in machine sector. Truncated after 1 year in corn sector.
30 ≤ rr1Operation of machine truncated in both sectors.
r1rr2Operation of machine truncated after 1 year in machine sector. Machine operated for 2 years in corn sector.
r2rrδMachine operated for two years in both sectors.
40 ≤ rr1Operation of machine truncated in both sectors.
r1rrγOperation of machine truncated after 1 year in machine sector. Machine operated for 2 years in corn sector.

One can tell a tale with this example by reading Figure 1 from right to left. Initially, managers of firms do not find it profitable to run a machine for more than one year in the machine sector. At a high rate of profits (or a low wage), they want to run the machine for two years in the corn sector. Meanwhile, the engineers are figuring out how to use less circulating capital with old machines in the sector manufacturing new machines. Eventually, as at the start, firms run machines in both sectors for one year for low rates of profits. But which sector they want to run machines for two years in at high rates of profits is reversed; at the end they run machines for two years only in the machine sector at high rates of profits. The above figure and table show this change coming about.

Table 2: Summary of Results
1Larger rate of profits associated with longer economic life of machine in machine sector
2Larger rate of profits associated with longer economic life of machine in machine sector; Recurrence of truncation in corn sector
3Larger rate of profits associated with longer economic life of machine in both sectors
4Larger rate of profits associated with longer economic life of machine in corn sector

The example can be used to highlight the falsity of outdated, archaic intuition associated with neoclassical and Austrian-school price theory. One might think that a desire of individuals to save more would be associated with an increased supply of capital. And this would drive the interest rate down. A lower interest rate would supposedly induce firms to adopt more capital-intensive techniques and to run machinery longer. The adoption of more capital-intensive techniques would, in turn, lead to greater output per worker. Around each switch point in the example, a lower interest rate is indeed associated with the adoption of a technique which provides greater output per head. (This property does not generalize, as shown by examples of capital-reversing, also known as positive real Wicksell effects.) But, in the example, a lower interest rate is associated with the truncation of the economic life of machines, except in the corn sector in Region 2. In that region, a lower interest rate is first associated with an increase of the economic life of the machine and then, for an even lower interest rate, a truncation of its life in the corn sector. The economic life of the machine does not even bear a monotonic relationship with the interest rate.

Notice that I am not arguing about aggregate measures of capital or the so-called average period of production. An analysis of prices of production shows that out-dated neoclassical and Austrian-school economists just have a faulty understanding of microeconomics, of how prices work.

I guess this example is something different than the recurrence of a process, given the specific manner in which fixed capital is involved. If you have thoroughly absorbed post Sraffian price theory, the recurrence of truncation is, I guess, no surprise. My contribution is in visualizing this possibility.