Monday, September 23, 2024

Where Do Prices Come From In Marginalist Economics?

1.0 Introduction

Where do prices come from in mainstream economics? As far as I know, some hard questions were raised half a century ago. They still have not been answered, I gather.

2.0 No Agent Makes Prices

Consider competitive markets, as defined in marginalist economics for most of the twentieth century. This implies that agents in the market take prices as given.

From Steve Keen, I know that if only a countable infinity of consumers and firms exist, the agents are systematically mistaken. Despite their beliefs, they are not atomic, and their actions in varying quantities bought or sold affect prices. For agents not to be systematically mistaken, an uncountable infinity of consumers and firms must exist.

I have noted Emmanuelle Benicourt making similar points before.

Classical political economy provides another concept of competitive markets. This concept is that no barriers to entry or exit exist. This concept has been taken into mainstream economics under the rubric of contestable markets.

If all agents take prices as given, who makes prices?

"How can equilibrium be established? ... Do individuals speculate on the equilibrium process? If they do, can the disequilibrium be regarded as, in some sense, a higher-order market process? Since no one has market power, no one sets prices; yet they are set and changed. There are no good answers to these questions." -- Kenneth Arrow (1987)

Franklin Fisher did some work here which he agrees is not a fully satisfactory answer. In his investigation of disequilibrium, convergence to an equilibria requires the ad-hoc assumption of 'No favourable suprise'. Furthermore, the equilibrium that is found will generally not correspond to the initial data. The disequilibrium process changes the data, for example, the initial distribution of endowments.

3.0 Equilibrium Paths?

Suppose one wants to model production. Many economists turned away from long run theory, towards analyzing intertemporal equilibrium paths. Even though I have done work in signal processing, I do not not feel comfortable with optimal control theory.

Some general objections can be raised to this whole approach. For example, initial endowments are among the givens. If some were previously produced, a failure to fulfill expectations is possible. But an equilibrium position is one in which all expectations are fulfilled in the future.

As I understand it, markets always clear at all moments in time along an equilibrium path. For given initial conditions, typically an uncountable infinity of such paths exist. Some of these paths result in the economy eventually reaching a point in which capital goods needed to keep the economy going are just not produced. Other paths approach a path for steady-state growth, from which they will eventually diverge. Frank Hahn argued that, given multiple capital goods, an infinite number of steady-state growth paths exist. How one of these paths is picked out is the 'Hahn problem'. Some paths neither lead to the economy collapsing or a steady state. Instead, they lead to cycles.

I am not clear what is typically assumed about expectations. I guess myopic expectations are needed, in some sense, for the existence of equilibrium paths that end up with the economy crashing.

Reswitching appears in this literature. Michael Bruno has a paper in Shell (1967) that has equilibrium paths just skipping over a reswitching regime. Rosser identifies this possibility with a cusp catastrophe. Maybe an issue arises here with how an equilibrium path can approach a steady state. Is this what Hahn refers to in the closing paragraphs of Hahn (1982).

I guess economists typically assume that the economy will not follow a path in which the economy cannot continue to be sustained. And initial prices are such that one unique path is picked out. Typically this path converges to a steady state growth path which has the stability of a saddle poing.

4.0 Conclusion

My references are not recent. Maybe I want to read something by William Brock. As far as I know, marginalist economic theory still has these problems. I guess mainstream economists just assume transversality conditions, with no theory of how equilibrium is reached or why the equilibrium path that is found does not lead to collapse.

References
  • Kenneth J. Arrow. 1987. Economic theory and the hypothesis of rationality, The New Pagrave: A Dictionary of Economics.
  • Robert Aumann. 1964. Markets with a continuum of traders. Econometrica, 32 (1-2): 39-50.
  • Emmanuelle Benicourt. 2016. Is the core e-Book a possible solution to our problems?, Real-World Economics Review, 75: 135-142
  • Robert Dorfman, Paul Samuelson, and Robert Solow. 1958. Linear Programming and Economic Analysis.
  • Franklin M. Fisher. 1983. Disequilibrium Foundations of Equilibrium Economics, Cambridge University Press.
  • Harvey Gram and G. C. Harcourt. 2017. Joan Robinson and MIT, History of Political Economy 49(3): 437-450.
  • Frank Hahn. 1982. The neo-Ricardians, Cambridge Journal of Economics 6(4): 353-374.
  • Frank Hahn. 1987. 'Hahn problem', The New Pagrave: A Dictionary of Economics.
  • J. Barkley Rosser Jr. 1983. Reswitching as a cusp catastrophe, Journal of Economic Theory 31(1): 182 - 193.
  • Karl Shell (ed.). 1967. Essays on the Theory of Economic Growth, MIT Press.

8 comments:

sturai said...

That paper from Michael Bruno seems interesting. There has been some literature on the convergence to steady states in the intertemporal case.

https://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/document?repid=rep1&type=pdf&doi=89532c6c7fb921e63690c444020b061dc320b05d

Robert Vienneau said...

Thanks. The Bruno article is beyond me. Thanks for the link to the Schefold article.

Anonymous said...

«Where do prices come from in mainstream economics? As far as I know, some hard questions were raised half a century ago. They still have not been answered, I gather.»

The traditional answer is "tâtonnement" which is a nice bit of hand-waving, but indeed has generated a lot of (pointless but sometimes interesting) debate, I just found this summary that to me seems mostly fair and cite several authors in common with this post:

http://www.hetwebsite.net/het/essays/stable/walrastatonnement.htm

Blissex said...

«competitive markets, as defined in marginalist economics for most of the twentieth century. This implies that agents in the market take prices as given.
From Steve Keen, I know that if only a countable infinity of consumers and firms exist, the agents are systematically mistaken.For agents not to be systematically mistaken, an uncountable infinity of consumers and firms must exist.»

The standard assumptions are not just infinite numbers of buyers and sellers, but also infinite numbers of markets including at every possible point in the future (which I think implies an infinite number of commodities), plus there must exactly one market participant (at least in the markets for capital commodities) impersonating those infinite number of buyers and sellers, plus other conditions to ensure that the optimization landscape has exactly one smooth peak. Under these conditions the second theorem of welfare theory still applies.

Anonymous said...

«If all agents take prices as given, who makes prices?»

I think that is not an issue and to me the question seems the result of a misunderstanding of the claim: which is that no single market participant has the *power* to *move* prices, it is the collective bidding of all powerless market participants that set prices. Prices "emerge" (from "tâtonnement" either notional or actual).

The scenario on which this is based is that of a town's market square (or "souk" in other countries), where all stalls selling eggs quickly converge on a single common price (the legendary "market price") for eggs, a scenario very familiar to pre-industrial political economists.

That is a scenario from a world very different from that of a set of suburbs each with a big Wal*mart.

Blissex said...

«equilibrium paths just skipping over a reswitching regime. Rosser identifies this possibility with a cusp catastrophe.»

All the assumptions of the Debreu-Arrow-Lucas models are designed to ensure a single smooth "dome" (or "bowls") of the optimization landscape, so that the distribution of income be univocally and solely determined by "factor productivity". Having multiple "domes" (or "bowls") already invalidates that as it makes the distribution of income path-dependent.

I have often wondered whether more realistic models not only have multiple local maxima (or minima) but also have not just cusps but other topological "catastrophes" or even simple things like saddle points (I guess so). My guess is that if these occur than powerful forces may be triggered to reshape the political economy to have a "nicer" optimization landscape to prevent instabilities.

JM Keynes pointed out that in actual economies most capital is long term and this acts as a ballast, but "minor" fluctuations can still be pretty painful, and attempts to fix them (e.g. "automatic stabilizers") may happen.

But then his intellectual successor HP Minsky pointed out that the interplay of risk expectations and momentum trading tends to make stability counter-productive as in "stabilizing an unstable, and his intellectual follower M Pettis by pointing out balance sheets effects created the concept of the "volatility machine". And here we are in 2024 ready to be crushed again by that machine.

Anonymous said...

«a town's market square [...] where all stalls selling eggs quickly converge on a single common price [...] a world very different from that of a set of suburbs each with a big Wal*mart.»

In the contemporary world there are colossal fixed costs and inflexibility related to gigantic and long lasting production runs of standardized products by a few huge producers, so these have had enormous incentives to shape politics and institutions to make those less risky and to eliminate uncertainty (for them, usually by transferring it to someone else, like the state/society or powerless individuals), again very different from the market square (or floating market) of a pre-industrial town.

https://www.inthailand.travel/floating-markets-of-thailand-guide/

Robert Vienneau said...

I know the word, 'souk' from Frank Herbert's Dune. I think Arrow is thinking of a general equilibrium, with all commodities bought and sold. Local markets in a specific place might be of interest and inspire formalization. I guess one complaint about marginalism is that not enough attention is paid to institutions. You might argue that mainstream economics now pays more attention.